Stephen Wandner, Urban Institute and W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research

“Unemployment compensation should permit such a worker, who becomes unemployed, to draw a cash benefit for a limited period during which there is expectation that he will soon be reemployed. This should be a contractual right not dependent on any means test.”

Report to the President of the Committee on Economic Security, January 1, 1935, p. 14.[1]

During the Great Depression, charitable contributions were insufficient to meaningfully assist needy unemployed workers. Charitable income support was both inadequate and demeaning to those who received it. Accordingly, President Franklin Roosevelt established the Committee on Economic Security to develop an unemployment insurance program, and the committee’s recommendations became the basis for the unemployment insurance provisions in the Social Security Act of 1935.

Unemployment insurance (UI) has long been defined as a form of social insurance that pays experienced workers who become unemployed through no fault of their own a portion of their former wages.  Because it is a social insurance program, it is paid as a matter of right to eligible unemployed workers, regardless of the financial needs of those workers. There is no means test. Thus, social insurance is like private insurance where payments are made to policyholders of fire or auto insurance, with no test of financial need, to compensate them for losses from fire or collisions.

Unlike almost all other nations of the world, UI benefits in the U.S. are paid for by insurance premiums (i.e., a UI tax) paid for by employers. In other countries, the program is called “unemployment compensation” or “unemployment assistance,” and is generally paid out of general revenue.

Experienced workers who have been laid off from their jobs receive UI benefits whether they are married or single, have children or not, have high incomes or low – as long as they meet state UI eligibility requirements.

Nonetheless, UI is subject to the same political pressures as any other public program. For example, in the mid-1970s, outrage over highly paid baseball players receiving UI benefits during the off-season resulted in a special federal statutory provision disqualifying this small group of workers from receiving benefits.

Today, the UI program is again under political pressure.  The new effort, however, would fundamentally transform the system by implementing a means test, such that UI would cease to be a social insurance program.  The Senate has just passed S.2149, a bill that provides for an extension of the Emergency Unemployment Compensation (EUC) program while denying such benefits to “Millionaires and Billionaires.”  Since the disqualification is for workers with an adjusted gross income of $1 million, the addition of language regarding “billionaires” is clearly political grandstanding; it has nothing to do with the substance of the provision.

Once again, politicians have chosen to focus on a perceived inequity, ignoring that the U.S. has an unemployment insurance program. Only as a non-insurance program could this issue be understood as a dangerous abuse by a few wealthy unemployed workers. Lawmakers are fomenting an emotional response to a problem that does not exist.

Do we want to terminate the UI program as insurance simply to prevent a few wealthy individuals who lose salaried jobs from collecting UI benefits like every other unemployed American  worker? (I will ignore here the immense administrative burden of enforcing this provision and the likelihood that the cost would exceed any UI benefit savings.)

Do we really want to make UI a means-tested program?  The key issue is: should our social insurance program for unemployed workers remain social insurance?  No matter what we think about the top !% of the income distribution, why should we sacrifice an effective eight-decade old social insurance program to make certain that the 1% do not receive insurance payments for which their employers paid their premiums into the Unemployment Trust Fund? Why do we want to destroy the UI program as a social insurance program to punish a handful of affluent recipients who receive no more in UI benefits than a typical middle-income worker? Do we want to undermine the UI program for the 99% to deny the 1% the insurance payments to which they are entitled? Does this false-populism issue justify the loss of legitimacy of a major social insurance program that has helped hundreds of millions of unemployed workers from the Great Depression though the Great Recession?


[1]Report to the President of the Committee on Economic Security, January 15, 1935, United States Printing Office, Washington: 1935, page 14.

Stephen Wandner is a Visiting Fellow at the Urban Institute and a Visiting Scholar at the W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment research.

6 Comments

  1. David Glueck April 9, 2014 at 4:41 pm - Reply

    Perhaps it is time to
    Perhaps it is time to estimate the costs and benefits. Once more our government is demonstrating its inability to distinguish between good policy and garbage.

    Fix immagration! Fix campaign regulation! Fix gun control!

  2. Don April 9, 2014 at 5:21 pm - Reply

    I think that UI should not be
    I think that UI should not be altered, expect during major economic down turns when benefits should be extended. I don’t think that one should be forced to take any job, especially a job that does not restore the person to where they were prior to loosing their job. We should support people with job training or retraining. And If the private sector is unwilling or unable to provide meaningful employment, them Government should step in and fill the void, until the economy turns around.

  3. Frank Neuhauser April 9, 2014 at 6:49 pm - Reply

    Stephan’s discussion is well
    Stephan’s discussion is well put. I’d add one more concern: High earners likely subsidize low earners in the UI system. Low income folks are much more commonly beneficiaries of UI, since UI is most important for high-turnover, seasonal, and part-time work. If we choose to deny benefits (which by the way are capped at very low levels) to highly paid workers, will those workers and their employer successfully lobby to get their wages excluded from UI payroll taxes? If so, the burden of this change will end up falling most heavily on the most needy. It is likely simple to develop the data and analysis to demonstrate the degree to which different wage group are +/- on UI contributions relative to benefits.

  4. hallmark.shelby@dol.gov April 9, 2014 at 6:55 pm - Reply

    Steve — glad to hear from
    Steve — glad to hear from you again! Completely agree with your piece, and with Frank Neuhauser’s explication of one way this misguided exclusion of the wealthy might very likely distort and undermine UI. Thanks for continuing the effort to protect the safety net.

    Shelby Hallmark

  5. Jim Ellenberger April 9, 2014 at 9:21 pm - Reply

    Thanks for your insight on
    Thanks for your insight on this Steve. It’s always good to remind folks of what this program is all about.

  6. Max J. Skidmore April 10, 2014 at 12:36 pm - Reply

    I agree that UI should remain
    I agree that UI should remain as is, and not exclude the wealthy. Such an exclusion would not result in significant savings. In any case, it’s an example of the program’s opponents seizing upon a justifiable concern that the wealthy should do more to pay their way, and converting that concern into a stealth attack upon a successful social program–an attack that would convert the program into “welfare,” and possibly even make it vulnerable to elimination.

Leave A Comment

How can we help you?

Media Inquiries
Sponsorship Opportunities
Membership
Partnerships

Stay up-to-date on the latest research & policy updates.

Subscribe to our newsletter